Thanks to Mark Drakeford, a long time supporter. Report in the paper
HousesCheaperBetterMore
"It's all about the Politics, Folks"
Search This Blog
Thursday, 12 June 2025
Wednesday, 11 June 2025
ANNUAL UPRATINGS The snag with LVT
The Irish Times 9 Jun 25 reports that “Local property tax bands and rates set to be changed to stave off big increases. Changes are being introduced to mitigate effects rising property values have on tax bills”
This is clearly a case of political funk
“Most homeowners will see modest increases in their local property tax (LPT)
next year under changes likely to be approved by the Cabinet this morning to
mitigate the effects rising property values have on tax bills.
The changes require legislation to widen tax bands and
reduce the rate of LPT, Minister for Finance Paschal Donohoe is
expected to tell colleagues.
Property
prices have increased by almost a quarter since the last revaluation
of properties for the tax in 2021. Fearing substantial hikes in tax bills, the
Government is expected to change the way the tax is calculated ahead of the
next date for revaluation on November 1st of this year.”
If there is one thing the taxpayer fears most and will
revolt against it’s a sudden jump, however justified, in a one-off tax charge. Fear
of the reaction to updating Rating Values was the main reason for the
introduction of Maggie’s much-hated Poll Tax. The idea of annual upratings of
Land Values is integral to every scheme of LVT that I’ve ever seen.
It seem to be a very cunning mechanism indeed to ratchet up
LVT by inflation as if by an inviable external hand. Of course the more LVT
rises to its maximum value the more its beneficial effects kick in. Tell that
to a granny in a corner-plot bungalow, living near a newly-opening Metro
station. Why should they pay 50% more on LVT for a transport facility they are
to frightened to use?
And the moral of this is?
Be very careful what you wish for! I’m all in favour of ‘Incremental
Improvement’ — making things better a bit at a time. Linking LVT to LV
inflation, with annual or even monthly upratings (c’mon we have the
technology!) seems a clever way of sugaring the pill. “Sure no one will notice
a 1% change”, or even “Go on, if they build a sewage works next door, your LVT
bill might go down!”.
Perhaps the maximalists are right. We must convince (force?)
the government to spend its political capital in implementing full-LVT. All
schemes involving sneaky uprating are doomed to be throttled by politicians’
funk.
Wednesday, 5 February 2025
FACT 5: YES, IT IS EXTRA BANK LENDING PUSHING UP PRICES,
Not house prices rising with banks running after them with bigger mortgages
This is a technical point to do with Correlation and
Causation which slick tricksters try to use to defend the banks’ immoral and
incontinent behaviour. So this is a bit longer than previous Facts.
has marched steadily upward with house prices,
while other forms of bank credit have tailed off,
as shown in this graph.
Does that prove higher prices were caused by looser lending? Not necessarily!
Here’s what J R-C says
“One concern with the view that increases in mortgage debt
drive up house prices
is that causation may run the other way: rising house prices
(caused by some other
factor, for example, inelastic supply or rising incomes)
lead to greater demand for
mortgage credit. However, there are reasons to be skeptical
of this view.
First, a number of recent empirical studies using
careful statistical identification
strategies, such as using financial deregulation as an
instrument exogeneous
to demand, suggest that house price rises are more likely to
be a response to
credit supply expansion rather than a cause. For example, in
one US study (q.v.)
the authors were able
to isolate the extent to which credit liberalisation was
exogeneous to demand in impacting mortgage credit
expansion and associated house price increases. This study
found that between
1994 and 2005, deregulation explained between one half and
two-thirds of the
observed increase in mortgage loans, and between one third
and one half of the
increase in house prices.
Second, other studies have found credit constraints
to be the most important factor in explaining cross-country differences
in house prices, which helps to explain different house price responses
to the same shifts in interest rates.
Third, the UK was not alone in seeing rapid expansions in
mortgage credit
correlated with rising house prices. For example, one study
found that across 16
high-income economies, on average, mortgage credit rose from
40% of GDP in
the mid-1990s to 70% by 2007, with house prices doubling
over the same period
Given significant differences in other potential explanatory variables in such
a large sample of countries, such as the elasticity of housing supply or
changes in income, expansion in mortgage debt, which occurred nearly
everywhere in the 1990s, is the most convincing intuitive explanation.
Indeed, recent cross-country empirical research shows
liberalising mortgage credit has actually led to
lower levels of home ownership
as affordability has worsened across many advanced economies.
Furthermore, rising mortgage debt and credit
liberalisation are not associated with increased
construction of new homes, as is
often claimed.”
Wednesday, 29 January 2025
Fact 4. Liberalised, predatory finance is the main driver of consumer demand and hence hyper-inflated prices
See how prices track lending (mortgages) step by step
“First, a number of recent empirical studies suggest that house price rises are more likely to be a response to credit supply expansion rather than a cause.
For example, a study found that between 1994 and 2005, US deregulation explained between one half and two-thirds of the observed increase in mortgage loans, and between one third and one half of the increase in house prices.
Second, other studies have found credit constraints to be the most important factor in explaining cross-country differences in house prices, which helps to explain different house price responses to the same shifts in interest rates.
Third, the UK was not alone in seeing rapid expansions in mortgage credit correlated with rising house prices.
For example, one study found that across 16 high-income economies, on average, mortgage credit rose from 40% of GDP in
the mid-1990s to 70% by 2007, with house prices doubling over the same period (see Figure 4 above).
Given all the differences in other potential explanatory variables
in such a large sample of countries, such as the elasticity of housing supply or changes in income, expansion in mortgage debt, which occurred nearly everywhere in the 1990s, is the most convincing intuitive explanation.
It gets worse! Research shows liberalising mortgage credit actually led to lower levels of home ownership as affordability has worsened across many advanced economies.
Furthermore, rising mortgage debt and credit liberalisation are not associated with
increased construction of new homes, as is often claimed.
Another explanation is that commercial home builders lack incentives to build out at a rate that would reduce house prices, even if more mortgage credit is being made available to theoretically support more construction.
As a result, more credit flows into competition for existing homes,
further inflating house prices and developer profits.
Monday, 27 January 2025
Fact 3. Buyers seek an asset (land with a house
on) and some also want a house (a commodity, a structure, a thing) to live in
BTL, landlords, 2nd homers, o'seas buyers of bolt-holes
are investors only.
Those looking for a place to live are both investors
and commodity buyers
Here’s what J R-C reminds us:
“Housing has two economic functions. It is both a
consumption good – it provides
shelter – but also an investment good. In relation to the
latter, residential property
can be:
• a financial asset providing
realised and unrealised capital gains, and actual
and imputed
rental returns;
• a source of collateral that can
enable borrowing and increase purchasing
power,
including to acquire additional property;
• a store, and means of passing
on, wealth; and
• a hedge against rental risk.
It is important for housing policy makers to understand the
impact of both types
of demand to ensure the efficacy of interventions aimed at
enhancing housing
affordability. The demand for housing as a consumption good
can be understood
as a universal need that the state has an obligation to
provide for at a basic
minimum level.”
Put simply: the economics of assets is not the
same as that for commodities — hence Fact 1: Build More won’t fix it.
Sunday, 26 January 2025
Fact 2. 'House' prices are not rising.
It's ONLY the Value of the PLOT
-the land the house is built on --
that is rising, not the Value of the Building.
Here’s how Josh explains this:
“Rising house prices in the UK and other high-income
economies have mainly
been driven by rising land values, with the cost of housing
structures tracking
consumer price inflation.
Land underlying dwellings in the UK has increased in nominal value almost eight-
fold since 1995, from £0.7 trillion in 1995 to £5.4 trillion.
This is equivalent to an increase from 82% to 252% of GDP.
From an economic theory perspective, capital gains and
rental income from
property are normally considered as economic rents – income
derived from
control over a scarce asset (land) needed for production –
rather than normal
profit derived from productive investment in a competitive market.
Land has unique properties differentiating it from other commodities,
including being inherently scarce, fixed and irreproducible,
which means its owners are able to extract economic rents
if permitted to do so. Increased financial flows into unproductive assets
like land and property increase such rents and can be viewed as
an inefficient allocation of capital, with negative consequences for economic
growth and wealth inequality.”
JR-C gets it! The conclusion that stopping land-price rises is the best fix.
(Although ‘only’ holding building costs shows a tech failure by the industry)
Sunday, 19 January 2025
Fact 1: Building Lots More Houses
will not fix it.
JR-C explains why.
Here’s what he says
“In UK policy circles, explanations of the affordability
crisis have focused more
on supply-side explanations. Multiple reviews of the UK’s
housing market have
concluded the reason for high prices is due to inadequate
provision of new
homes relative to rising demand driven by rising incomes,
increasing household
formation (people living in smaller households) and rising
immigration. Government
interventions have also focused on supply-side reforms.
However, since the 1980s, successive governments have been
unable to
materially increase the rate of housebuilding, which has
averaged around 150,000
new units per year.2 The UK housing development sector is
dominated by private
sector developers, who may lack incentives to build out at a
rate that would reduce
house prices in local areas where they operate.3–5
Moreover, evidence suggests that expansion of the housing
stock may have a
limited effect on housing affordability in aggregate.
Estimates of the sensitivity
of UK house prices to increases in housing stock
consistently show that
a
1% increase in housing stock delivers a 1.5–2% reduction
in house prices.6,7
[that’s quite impressive? Elastic demand. A bit cheaper
and we’d want(buy) lots more.]
Taking into account the growing surplus of housing stock
relative to number
of households, this implies that, all else equal, expanding
the housing stock by
20% (approximately 5 million homes) over the next 20 years
roughly in line with
government projections might bring down prices by around
10%.7 This contrasts
with a 306% increase in mean nominal English house prices
since January 2000
(from £75,219 to £305,370).8
[That’s what he says: Actual prices rose 306% over the last
20 years.
So even if we could have built 400,000 homes p.a., it
only would have reduced prices by 10%!
TEN per cent drop on a total rise of THREE HUNDRED AND SIX
per cent! ]
Furthermore, new build makes up just 1% of the total of new
housing supply that
comes onto the market each year, with the vast majority
coming from existing
properties being sold or rented out.9 To achieve more
material increases in
affordability in the short to medium term, policy makers
also need to consider how
to reduce types of demand – specifically investment demand –
that might free up
existing stock for those in housing need, as well as
ensuring the most efficient use
of any new supply.”
[The clowns who advocate ‘Build More’ as the fix for the
Housing Price Crisis haven’t a clue.]
Based on
Ryan-Collins, R. (2024). The demand for
housing as an investment: Drivers, outcomes and
policy interventions to enhance housing affordability in the UK. UCL
Institute for Innovation and Public Purpose, Policy Report
2024/13.
Available
at: https://www.ucl.ac.uk/bartlett/public-purpose/policyreport-2024-13.
Filed at HML/HousingMarket/Invest