[Hint: Very few Owner-Occupiers]
Using data from a range of sources, this paper makes estimates of the money flows associated with home-ownership in 2000. Of particular interest is the identification of 'winners' and 'losers' in the owner-occupied sector. The big winners are of course Financial Institutions, the Government and those involved in transactions -- solicitors etc. Very little of the money going in to the system reaches the producers of housing (builders), landowners. The most paltry sums reach those who inherit the accumulated wealth of housing, even fewer owner-occupiers make a financial gain in their lifetime. This is a paper I read in 2002.
Using data from a range of sources, this paper makes estimates of the money flows associated with home-ownership in 2000. Of particular interest is the identification of 'winners' and 'losers' in the owner-occupied sector. The big winners are of course Financial Institutions, the Government and those involved in transactions -- solicitors etc. Very little of the money going in to the system reaches the producers of housing (builders), landowners. The most paltry sums reach those who inherit the accumulated wealth of housing, even fewer owner-occupiers make a financial gain in their lifetime. This is a paper I read in 2002.
— Where does the money go, and who
makes money out of owner-occupation?
— How is this flow of money related
to the overall money system and the economy?
It is
surprising that in a field so rich in published data and of such wide interest
to discover that the answers to such relevant questions are not immediately
available. I have had to piece together the answers from a variety of sources,
including previously published work and by using some heroic assumptions. I
reach a conclusion — that buying your own home in the UK is a pretty lousy
investment — which runs counter to conventional wisdom.
Throughout this paper I have used
values for the Year 2000 which relate to the whole of the United Kingdom. The
sources for all the figures used and the methods of calculation are shown in an
Appendix. I would be grateful for any corrections, or to discuss my
methodology. I have chosen in the main to look at the sector in aggregate,
lumping together a vast range of individual experiences. Nothing I say runs
counter to the possibility that individuals might be losers in a boom or
winners during a slump.
[Note: I
have ignored the imputed value of the rent 'paid' by the occupier to the owner,
who is the same person. One reason for this omission is that it is not an actual flow. 'Shadow rents' could
be calculated, values I believe have little meaning in the market so distorted
by land-values.]
*The Appendix explains how the
numbers have been derived, and what assumptions have been made.
1.
Where does the money go?
1.1 Net Equity
'The Big Barrel' £1,100 bn
In the
diagram (Figure 1) I have pictured the total value of the 16.5 mn
owner-occupied houses in the UK as a barrel of money. This is known as Equity —
not real spendable money, but a measure at current market prices of the value
of entire estate of privately owned dwellings in the UK. Net Equity is the
total value less the mortgage debt outstanding (£500 bn). To put these numbers
into context, the total GNP of the UK was about £1,000 bn in 2000.
Comment:
The home-owners debt-to-equity ratio is 'prudent', with only 30% of equity owed
as debt. Of course individual owners may have debt/equity ratios of 90%, which
may lead to the 'negative equity trap' should house prices fall. This happened
during the early 1990's and affected millions. But negative equity is only a
problem when the borrower wants to sell, or is unable to service his or her
debt.
1.2 Mortgage Debt
'The small barrel' £500 bn
This debt
is an asset of the financial sector. It is held by the traditional Building
Societies but the major proportion of the debt is held by the clearing Banks.
1.3 Mortgage
Interest an outflow of £37.5
This is the
first flow of money, which is paid out by home-owners who are borrowers. About
half of all owners are in debt, and repayment is subject to interest rates
which vary with the market, creating unpredictable liabilities for the home-buyer.
1.4 Net Mortgage
Lending an inflow of £44.0 bn
In Figure 1
this is shown as a positive inflow to the Net Equity barrel. There are
substantial flows of capital (money) both to and from the financial sector:—
— Capital flows to the financial
sector as repayment of mortgage debt, and
— Capital comes from the financial
sector as new advances which are secured on the collateral value of the housing
equity, mainly related to house purchase.
It is usual
for the total amount of mortgage debt to grow year-on-year. To sustain this
requires fresh supplies of credit from Finance sector.
1.5 'Over-borrowing'
an outflow of £9.7 bn
Over-borrowing,
or Mortgage Equity Withdrawal (MEW) as it is styled by the Bank of England, is
mortgage lending which is used for something other than house purchase. In the
past borrowing for house- purchase attracted tax relief (It still does in many
countries) So MEW in the UK is just a normal financial transaction. This kind
of borrowing is portrayed as a major benefit of home-owning, with owners
feeling more confident as their house prices rise. But it is still borrowing,
and on no more favourable terms than any other commercial loans. All the moneys
will have to be repaid together with interest charges. Ability to repay is more
important to the lenders than the size of the collateral represented by the
market price of the house.
1.6 Housing
Payments .. an inflow of £68.5 bn
Apart from
Net Mortgage Lending, this is the only other cash flow into the barrel. It
covers all the costs related to purchasing, owning and selling house property.
The main destination for these payments — mortgage interest - has been
explained already. The next sections break down the destination for the other
outflows.
Comment:
This huge amount of money takes a large chunk out of the household budget —
about 16%. As the UK economy has progressed the proportions of the family
budget spent on food and clothing have fallen dramatically in the last 50
years. The proportion spent on housing has remained stubbornly high.
1.7 The
Housebuilders an outflow of £12.6 bn
The
Housebuilders produce the new houses, and have been responsible for producing
all the houses which form the basis for the equity discussed here. Less than
one-fifth of the total of home-owners expenditure on house-purchase reaches the
Housebuilders, and a large proportion of that goes to the owners of land
acquired for new building.
1.8 Transactions
Costs an outflow of £8.5 bn
For every
new-built house produced, there are about 10 old ones traded. Transaction costs
only affects the million or so traders. These costs are relatively low in the
UK compared to Continental Europe, and. attempts are being made through the
introduction of a Seller's Pack to lessen these costs further.
1.9 Government,
Central and Local an outflow of £30.5 bn
Taxes on
the ownership and transfer of property (plus another crypto-tax to be described
in the next section) are actual outflows of money. Not included are tax
exemptions on incomes or capital gains. My concern here is to trace actual as
opposed to potential flows of money. However, two tax breaks in particular give
a major boost to house purchase compared to other types of investment:
— Capital
Gains Tax on the potentially huge gains are free of tax for one's main
residence
— Imputed Rent is the rent that would be paid by the
occupier-tenant to the landlord-owner, but which remains hypothetical because
the owner and the occupier are the same person. No tax is levied on this
benefit.
We now come
to four categories of home-owners, or ex-home-owners who are in receipt of
significant amounts of money. Apart from the 'Traders Down', these are the
'Last Time Sellers'
The
category 'transfer to rented accommodation' is a quite large group - about
180,000 households per year . Many of these will be elderly people going into
sheltered accommodation. About 70,000 of these will be subject to a type of
equity confiscation, the 'crypto-tax' referred to in the last section: The
proceeds of the sale of their house will be taken by the State to pay for their
residential care. (report in The Guardian 30 May 2001). Hamnett (1991) reported
that in the 1980s social policy analysts had readily identified that "home
equity release would play an increasing role in financing elderly care"
(p9) The benefits to the home-owner of this form of 'equity confiscation' are
not immediately obvious, especially when those who have not saved will be paid
for in full by Social Security.
1.11.
Last Time Sellers: Divorcees and Emigrants: outflow of £1.0 bn
These two
groups don't make very much money, and their personal circumstances may in any
case create additional major expense.
1.12
Last Time Sellers: Inheritors: outflow £7.5 bn
The final
category of last-time sellers results from the death of the home-owner, and is
"the most important route for equity withdrawal" according to Hamnett
(p7). The beneficiaries of this are of course not the home owners, but those
who inherit the property after their death. Great hopes were placed in this
process for spreading wealth more widely in society, but the results have so
far disappointed. About 180,000 properties were inherited during 2000, with an
average net value of £42,000. The amount of inherited personal housing wealth
is thus about £7.5 bn, which if spread evenly could hugely aid the poorest in
society. But inheritance as a social leveller has two major drawbacks
identified by Hamnett: it comes too late in life - typically an inheritor is
about 50 years old, and by keeping it in the family the recipients are
generally housing-rich already. The upshot is that the legacy is largely
re-invested in financial instruments or in further property purchases. It is a
natural human impulse to want to leave something for your children's financial
security, but the home-owning route only helps a minority who either don't need
it or who get it too late in life.
1.13
Traders Down: an outflow of £2.3 bn
There is
one category of home-owner who is still alive to enjoy a real payoff from the
house-buying, house- mortgaging and house-selling game. Those who sell-up and
move into a cheaper property, a rented property or move in with someone else,
stand to make real spendable money without any obligation to repay. Holmans
(1991) estimated that in 1985 there were about 80,000 households who made a
seemingly modest £8,000 from the trade-down. Westway (1993) speculated that
this could reach 130,000 by the year 2000 with an average 'take' of £17,700, yielding
a total of £2.3 bn of free equity turned into cash. This would generally accrue
to owners who had typically been paying off a mortgage for 20 to 30 years.
____________________________________
This
completes the answers to the first part, which traces the actual cash flows
around home ownership and the equity in housing. Later I will look at whether
home-owning really offers such a good return to the owner-investor, but now I
want to put housing finance in the context of the wider economy:
2.0 Housing
Finance and the wider Economy
2.1 Payouts to
depositors and Bank shareholders
Maintaining
a financial clearing system is vital to the running of an economy, but it has
to be paid for. The biggest contributor to revenue are mortgage borrowers. The
sector waxes fat on the constant churning of mortgaging and re-mortgaging,
collecting enormous sums by way of interest. Much of this goes to maintaining
the lavish network of offices and processing systems. The rest is paid out as
interest to savers, and as dividends for shareholders. All of this has to be
paid for by the homeowner: there is no other source of money flowing into the
home-owning system. Hamnett (1991) describes this (p38) as robbing Peter to pay
Paul: That the bulk of existing owners capital gains (presumably he means
realised gains) are paid for by new buyers entering the market for the first
time or by existing owners trading up and taking a larger mortgage. A less
charitable view might be that this is a gigantic pyramid scam.
2.2 Driving the Economy
by borrowing and spending
"In
this economic recovery (Q1, 2002) homes have done much more than shelter people
from the wind and rain. They have helped shelter the whole world from deep
recession" says the Economist in a leading article on 30th March,
2002. The confidence of home-owners borne of rising house prices both in the UK
but especially in the US enables them to borrow to spend. This keeps the
economy buoyant.
Equity
withdrawal in the year 2000 amounted to £9.7 bn., which added about 1.5% to
households spending power (Bank of England figures). Mortgage Equity
Withdrawers particularly vexes the Bank of England monetary policy group. There
is good reason to watch them: In the last housing boom in 1988, the Bank failed
to notice that consumers purchasing power had been expanded by 8% through this
technique. Conversely, if house prices slump, or home owners lose confidence
this form of borrowing and spending, it can rapidly dry up. Without some
alternative driver for the economy, it could head into deep recession
2.3
Mortgaging and the Money System
As Michael
Rowbotham (1998) explains: Governments used to issue most of the new money that
was needed to keep the economy moving. Since WW2 they have gradually abandoned
their own issue of money and left it to commercial banks to create new money.
But Banks don't just give or spend this money: they lend it and expect it to be
repaid with interest. Today about 97% of all the money in the economy has
originated in this way. Only a paltry 3% has been issued by government free of
interest and repayment. The abandonment by sovereign governments of control
over the issue of our own money is a story that is glossed over by economists.
But of course, as the Japanese financial sector has discovered, offering loans on
the collateral of property even at very low rates of interest, won't get the
money into the economy unless there are borrowers to take it up. No borrowers,
no loans: No loans no new money to keep the economy moving.
So where in the economy are the bankers
going to find borrowers who are eager to take out big loans, and eager to come
back for more? This is where the mortgaged home-owner comes in. Egged on by the
prospect of easy capital gains, house-purchasers borrow to the hilt. Two-thirds
of the total money stock in the UK and a massive 80% in the US has derived from
mortgages related to house buying. The mortgage, 'the pledge of death' in Old
French (Chambers dictionary, 1990), is the principal pump and conduit for
getting money into the economy. There could be other ways of producing new
money: Government could reclaim its seigniorage and issue the money directly
(to pay for the London Underground perhaps?). Banks could lend 'on personal
recognisance' — purely on their knowledge of the borrower. No, it's the housing
market and the equity that it offers that is the preferred vehicle for lazy
bankers to deliver fresh credit into the economy.
___________________________________________________
3
HOME-OWNING: The balance sheet
3.1
An Englishman's home
But what of
the house buyers who find themselves in this 'death-pledge'? Is it worthwhile?
Do they gain? As far back as 1979 Margaret Thatcher was in no doubt about the
benefits of buying a house with a mortgage: ".. .property owning
democracy.. .give more of our people freedom and mobility.. .prospect of
handing on something to our children and grandchildren.". Ten years on,
Nigel Lawson echoed this, that Britain, through home-owning had become
"..a nation of inheritors" leading to a "..further diffusion of
property in society". (quotes given in Hamnett, 1991) In a market where
house prices are constantly rising, this golden scenario seems to be
self-evident. Home-owners feel good as their property gains in value. The sound
conventional advice is to constantly trade up, increase your equity, take out
the biggest mortgage you can. Rising house prices will wipe out the pain, and
you can look forward to becoming a quarter or a half- millionaire in a few
years time. It is such an attractive prospect, a one-way path to riches, that
it is not surprising that two-thirds of British households buy into home-owning
with a mortgage.
The British obsession with
home-owning, is memorably summed up by the phrase 'an Englishman's home is his
castle'. This reminds us that the satisfaction delivered by home-owning is more
than financial - the historical association of voting rights with property
ownership conveys a fundamental idea of liberty and stake-holding in the
community. Such sentiments should not be lightly cast aside. Having the freedom
to do as one likes in one's own home compares especially favourably with the
rented sector, particularly renting from the local authority. Politicians like
Margaret Thatcher were quick to realise the vote-winning potential of the
right-to-buy your council house.
Conventional
wisdom has it that buying your own home is cheaper than renting. Of course such
comparisons are not comparing like with like: In the UK there is a limited
supply of main-stream rented accommodation. Nevertheless, the Abbey National
(mortgage Bank) confidently asserts that 'house buyers are 30% better off than
tenants' (April, 2002). The gap between renting and buying has been narrowing
in recent years, and would be completely wiped out for those who wish to move
frequently.
3.3 As an
Investment :
Although
owning a house as a place to live in is probably financially sound, this is not
the main motivation for buying. Investment, in the sense of building up a
valuable asset is paramount. Anecdotal evidence abounds that even a house of
great architectural bravura will frequently be difficult to sell, because
buyers are worried about future resale. It is the views of the mortgage valuer,
not potential purchaser that determines the 'value' of a property, and houses
however spacious or attractive, if blighted by the valuers, it will not re-sell
easily or at a good price. Buyers place potential capital gain above all other
features including the quality of the house as a place to live.
But judged by this criterion,
housing is a very poor investment. While capital values may rise steadily,
which fills the owners with the confidence to borrow and spend, the real
payoffs are meagre indeed. Only the traders-down pocket some real money which
they can spend as they like: The global amount extracted in this way was about
£2.3 bn on a net equity value of the UK owner-occupied housing stock of about
£1,100 bn The much-hyped investment in housing yields the investor-owners a
miserly 0.2% overall. Even if we include the £7.5 bn extracted from housing by
the inheritors (mostly your relations) the yield is
(£2.3 + £7.5)/£1,100 *100 = 0.9%
The
continuing enthusiasm of buyers to borrow to invest in housing seems difficult
to explain.
References:
Abbey National (April, 2002) Renting & Buying
Guide Abbey National Bank, London (internet: www.abbeynational.co.uk )
Bank of England (2001) Inflation Report (internet:
www.bankofengland.co.uk)
Hamnett, Chris; Harmer, Michael and
Williams, Peter
(1991) Safe as houses: Housing inheritance in Britain Paul Chapman, London
Holmans, A E (1991) Estimates of housing equity
withdrawal by owner occupiers in the united Kingdom; 1970 to 1990 Government
Economic Service Working Ppaer No 116
Rowbotham, Michael (1998) The Grip of Death: A study
of modern money, debt slavery and destructive economics, Jon Carpenter
Publishing, Oxfordshire £15.
Oswald, Andrew (2001) Buying: Why it's bad for
you The Guardian Weekend , London Aug 4th 2001
The Economist Big scary monsters: Mortgage
lending agencies in America July 19th 2001
Westway, Peter F (Nov, 1993) Mortgage equity
withdrawal: Causes and Consequences Discussion paper no. 59, National Institute
of Economic and Social Research, London
_____________________________________
Derivation of numbers and values
involved in house trading (in the Diagram: Where does the money go?)
Sources of
data are in the main UK Government, published by the ONS (Office for National
Statistics), H M Treasury or the Bank of England (BoE). As far as possible,
values are based on the year 2000, although this varies between calendar and
fiscal years. Figures relate to the U.K. which has sometimes meant that numbers
published for England or England and Wales have had to be adjusted upwards.
Two major studies have been carried
out to derive similar numbers, and are based on a much fuller working-over of
the data: Holmans (1991) with later re-working and extension by Westway (1993).
Both especially Westway have projected forward their figures to 2000 and
beyond, but neither could have fully anticipated the depth of the slump in the
housing market from 1991 to 1997, so some figures may be too high or low as a
result. Overall though, I believe I have identified the appropriate scale of
the numbers involved.
HOUSING
EQUITY: There are 20.7 mn households in England of which 68% are owner-
occupied. Average house prices quoted by Nationwide in 2000: £102,000.
Hence Gross
Equity = £1,435 bn for England x 1.1 = ~£1,600 bn for UK.
Total
Lending to individuals secured on property, i.e. 'mortgages' = £500 bn
(representing 81% of all borrowing by individuals)
Hence Net
Equity in Housing = £1,600 - £500 = £1,100 bn
(This
compares with the figure of ??£2.3 tn quoted by the CEBR in 2002, but which
includes social and private rented property as well)
INPUTS to
'Housing Equity':
Housing
payments: £68.5 bn by 16,500,000:
By
Homeowners: who spend 16% of their net income on 'Housing', and hardly varies
across the income quintiles (Family Expenditure Survey) This includes all
payments: mortgage interest and loan repayment, deposits(? I am not sure if
this constitutes a capital transaction; in any case it would greatly increase
the input by owners, and strengthen my case), as well as repairs, insurance,
council tax. Assuming that the owners come from the top 3 quintiles of earners
then they expend (£61.1 + £63.4 + £117.9) / 3 = £79.9 per week or £4159 p.a. on
housing. Muliplying up by the number of owner-occupied houses (16.5 million)
gives total expenditure of £68.5 bn by home-owners on housing during 2000.
Net
mortgage payments £44.0 bn by 1,500,000
There
are huge flows of mortgage lending and repayment, but the balance calculated by
BoE is +£44.0 bn. Of course this item could be negative: home-owners paying off
more loans than they were taking out, as was the case during most of the
1990's.
OUTPUTS from Housing Equity
Transaction
Costs £8.5 bn:
Land
Registry records ~900,000 property transfers during 2000 in England & Wales
(say 950,000 for U.K). Assume each one generates £9,000 revenues for the
solicitors, estate agents, movers etc
Government
- central, local £30.5 bn
H.M.
Treasury record for fiscal 2000-1 that Inheritance tax £2.2 bn('death duties),
Stamp duty £8.2 bnand Council Tax £13.9 bn add up to £24.3 bn. The remainder
£6.2 bn (which I derived by balancing out all other inputs and outputs) could
be made up of VAT on repairs and alterations, CGT where applicable eg on second
homes etc
£500
bn mortgage debt (BoE above) at 7.5% interest (average mortgage for 2000, BoE).
This may be an under-estimate, since many loans are secured at much higher
rates of interest.
House
Builders: £12.6 bn 120,000
New-build
for the private sector (Housing and Construction Statistics) remains at a very
low level of 120,000 (implying a life-span of 138 years if all were built as
replacements for obsolete houses). Average new-build price - £105,000
(Nationwide). The figure of 50% for land value is based on typical building
costs (Building Cost Information Services), hence 'Landowners' receive ~£6.3 bn
for new build.
Over-borrowers:
£9.7 bn 800,000
This
is the classic equity withdrawal, where movers do not fully reinvest proceeds
of sale, or non-movers take out additional mortgages. (BoE provide detailed
analysis of this)
Renting,
Residential £2.9 bn 70,000
Inheritors
£7.5 bn 180,000
Traders-down
£2.3 bn 130,000
Divorcees,
emigrants £1.0 bn 130,000
The main
source for these four categories is the work of Holmans, extended by Westway.
Some of the values produced are suspect, especially when it involves
extrapolating 1990 values forward to 2000, but are nevertheless of the right
order:
Last-time
movers include the deceased - about 180,000 households who leave £24,000 (Holmans).
This seems low, but is worth remembering the circumstances.
Move to
residential includes those whose equity is confiscated to pay for residential
care, hence the (unspecified) connection back into Government.
Traders
down which Holmans identified as numbering 58,000 in 1987 and would expand to
130,000 by 2000. Holmans attached the very modest value of £8,000 pay-off. I
have increased this to £17,700.
[1]
Conall Boyle, (in 2002) Department of Construction and Surveying, University of
Central England, now Birmingham City University. Currently an independent
researcher: Contact conall@fsmail.net This paper was presented at an RICS
Conference, Glasgow September 2002.
No comments:
Post a Comment